Friday, May 23, 2014

A Review of Policy Design in Mitigating Carbon Emissions - Carbon Tax or Trading

In 2009, the House of Representatives narrowly passed the American Clean Energy and Security Act (ACES) (H.R.2454) by a vote of 219-212. The bill proposed a carbon cap-and-trade system and was seen as US’s answer on its commitment towards climate change to the then upcoming Copenhagen Climate Summit. However, the bill failed to pass the Senate. This paper seeks to review how policy design favored cap-and-trade over carbon tax, and suggests reasons for it failing to be passed.

Carbon Tax: A Penalty to All

Economically, a carbon tax is the most direct and efficient approach to curbing carbon emissions. It directly accounts for the social costs associated with greenhouse gas emissions. A published tax rate provides certainty on the tax amount payable. However, it is uncertainty if the pricing mechanism would effectively reduce emissions.

What is clear with a carbon tax is that it presents a clear message of “You use, you pay”, and a perception of “No Way Out”. Consumers will most likely be at the receiving end as businesses passes the additional costs to them. The carbon tax is also seen as a regressive tax that affects the poor in particular especially when applied to goods such as energy and food which are price inelastic. Businesses could also suffer as they lose the competition in the global economy.

Many overseas countries are facing similar problems when imposing a carbon tax. An example was Australia, where former Prime Minister Julia Gillard’s carbon tax cost resulted in her Labor-Greens coalition government being voted out, and the current government plans to reverse the unpopular ruling. These various factors presents a lose-lose-lose situation, which could explain the lean towards a cap-and-trade approach.

Carbon Trading: Market Driven Approach

The market driven cap-and-trade system provides a “Way Out” for businesses and industries, as companies that are energy efficient could sell their allowances to net emitters. This mimics the Acid Rain program to limit SO2 levels. Market forces manage the pricing, whilst the invisible hand of the government controls by setting the emission limit. Such a cap also provides certainty on achieving the original intent – to mitigate greenhouse emission levels. 

A key issue lies with the amount of greenhouse gases to limit. An overly-high limit poses little effect and drives down the carbon costs, which might disincentive industries to adopt greater energy efficiency, as they choose to acquire additional allowances. Such was the case when the EU introduced its emissions trading program, where a higher emissions limit was set. Conversely, an exceptionally-low limit could artificially inflate costs, affecting costing of goods and global competitiveness. The government would not benefit from a cap-and-trade program if the initial allocation of allowances was free, or “grandfathering”, compared to the carbon tax, which would provide tax revenue that could be channeled to other social and environmental initiatives.

An Elites’ Debate


Through my research, it is apparent that elites and organized interests groups dominated the debates. There were questions on the approach to manage emissions, the social costs to impose, and whether climate change is actually happening. In contrast, the public, whilst generally believing in climate change, have not mobilized towards the cause. The cost-benefit simply does not make sense. The cost associated with the legislation would be too high, with no clear benefit especially when greenhouse emission is a global issue. Why should Americans pay a penalty for their carbon emissions when other countries could freely pollute. Without global consensus, any governmental actions on emission levels would at best be a symbolic gesture, much like the ACES act. That could explain why the focus has shifted towards encouraging greater energy efficiency and renewable energy generation. 

(606 words)

References:




No comments:

Post a Comment